Such structures offer benefits such as providing insurance and reinsurance companies with greater stability of cash flows associated with natural hazards, something that extreme weather events are impacting under the current insurance model. These structures also balance private insurers’ loss of market share of insuring natural hazards by allowing them to purchase the risk on the back side of the market. CLRTs would provide catastrophic risk protection by the FNHIC, the optimal entity for absorbing that risk given its GSE status.
These structures raise the question of whether an implicit or explicit guarantee would be provided on the FNHIC’s debt. A case could be made for either option. The existence of some form of guarantee would lower the FNHIC’s debt costs but raise its risk to taxpayers in the event of a major catastrophe. Policymakers could consider alternative models to a purely federal, GSE structure, though. A cooperative-style, private model would have insurers and reinsurers inject capital into an entity that pools catastrophic risk. That structure would reduce taxpayers’ exposure but may not provide adequate coverage at the scale required.
A Test Case For CLRTs
To illustrate the mechanics of the CLRT security, consider a reference pool with a notional value of $500 million consisting of FNHIC insurance policies with broad geographic distribution and $400,000 per home in coverage against natural hazard risk. Homeowners incur deductibles ranging between $1,000 and $10,000. The CLRT has a one-year term reflecting homeowners policy terms, though the issuance of an annual policy could be revisited by FNHIC – offering multi-year policies could add more stability to the homeowner and the CLRT market.
The FNHIC takes the first 50 basis points of losses on the pool. The junior tranche takes the next 100 basis points, the mezzanine tranche absorbs the next 300 basis points of losses, and the senior tranche takes the last 200 basis points for a total loss subordination of 650 basis points (6.5%), before the FNHIC picks up any catastrophic losses.
The structure assumes the FNHIC would take 500 basis points (5%) of the losses in each of the private tranches. A summary of the notional value of each tranche and loss allocation is shown in Figure 3.
If over the course of a year actual losses were 5%, the FNHIC would absorb the first $2.5 million of loss. The junior tranche would take $4.75 million in losses (adjusted for the 5% side-by-side risk by the FNHIC), with the mezzanine tranche picking up $14.25 million and the senior tranche taking the remaining $2.38 million. In this example, the FNHIC bears a total of $3.62 million ($2.5 million first loss plus $1.12 million in side-by-side losses for each of the private tranches).
Each tranche investor would bid on their CLRT tranche based on their assessment of the distribution of losses that could be realized.
The FNHIC would stabilize the market for homeowners insurance by providing greater certainty to insurers and reinsurers by way of their participation in CLRTs. Over time, this should lower the cost of homeowners’ policies and ensure that no homeowner can be dropped from a policy based solely on the location of their property. It should also ensure that, in the near-term, no regions of the country are completely devoid of catastrophic, natural hazard-related coverage.
Benefits And Challenges Of National Hazard Insurance
While private insurers would still need to seek approval from state insurance commissions on standard homeowners policies, the issues they face today in obtaining rate approval on policies related to natural hazard exposures would no longer exist given the FNHIC’s national hazard insurance preemption. Another benefit of the FNHIC model is that it removes taxpayers from the direct exposure to natural hazard losses on flood insurance by folding the NFIP into the FNHIC.
Over the years, NFIP has significantly underpriced the costs of flooding such that the program is roughly $20.5 billion in debt to the U.S. Treasury. Moving the NFIP off of the government’s books will reduce that direct exposure. Establishing the FNHIC as a standalone, publicly traded GSE would ensure its operational solvency while maximizing returns for shareholders. That structure, in turn, would reduce long-term exposure to taxpayers from indirect losses.
The GSE model also provides a mechanism for offering subsidies to low- and moderate-income homeowners that today are unavailable. A national hazard insurance program would reduce risks to the housing GSEs and other credit investors, as well as provide certainty surrounding the availability of homeowners insurance for the housing finance system. The FNHIC would eliminate the need for state-run property insurance programs, providing significant savings both for consumers and taxpayers while reducing state-by-state exposures.
Establishing the FNHIC carries a number of financial, political, and operational challenges.
The financial requirements to capitalize the FNHIC would be daunting, to say the least. To gain a sense of the magnitude of cost, consider that between 2014 and 2023 insured losses associated with natural disasters ranged from $29.9 billion in 2015 to $163.9 billion in 2017, according to the Insurance Information Institute’s figures. Losses averaged $78.3 billion annually over that period.
Assuming a stress loss that is three times the average in order to approximate an extreme outcome, the total stress losses for natural hazards would be roughly $235 billion annually. By comparison, the cost to recapitalize Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae has been estimated at $150 billion. The largest U.S. initial public offering (IPO) to date was Alibaba Group Holding Limited, in 2014, at $22 billion in 2014. These reference points underscore the heavy up-front financing requirements to get the FNHIC off the ground.